• addiction to debt has widened inequality, -- and crippled the world eco

    From a425couple@21:1/5 to All on Tue Jul 2 15:39:51 2024
    XPost: or.politics, ca.politics, seattle.politics
    XPost: alt.law-enforcement

    a key
    “The way we are living is not normal. We have become so addicted to debt
    that we are borrowing more than two times as much as we used to, for the
    same dollar of income that the economy is generating.”

    from https://www.analystnews.org/posts/how-our-global-addiction-to-debt-has-widened-inequality-hacked-democracy-and-crippled-the-world-economy

    How the global addiction to debt has widened inequality, hacked
    democracy and crippled the world economy

    We’re living in dysfunctional times. Princeton economist Atif Mian says
    the ‘debt supercycle’ is at the root of it all — and it’s only going to get worse.
    BY ISMAT MANGLA
    JUNE 25, 2024
    Cover Image for How the global addiction to debt has widened inequality,
    hacked democracy and crippled the world economy
    Princeton economist Atif Mian says our addiction to debt imperils the
    world economy.

    AYSHA KHAN

    Ten years ago, Princeton economist Atif Mian and his research partner, University of Chicago economist Amir Sufi, published House of Debt: How
    They (and You) Caused the Great Recession, and How We Can Prevent It
    from Happening Again. The book argued, convincingly and with powerful
    data, that severe recessions — including the 2008 Great Recession — are caused by a huge buildup of consumer debt, followed by a drop in
    household spending that exacerbates job losses and economic slowdowns.

    Mian and Sufi posited that the focus on only bailing out banks and
    financial institutions, rather than addressing the household debt
    problem through forgiving or restructuring debt, hindered economic
    recovery in 2008. House of Debt, which former U.S. Treasury Secretary
    Larry Summers called 2014’s most important economics book, challenged traditional views on the causes and remedies of the financial crisis and
    was widely hailed as groundbreaking.

    In the decade since, Mian has zoomed out to examine how “our addiction
    to debt” has thrust the world economy into crisis. In a recent article
    for the International Monetary Fund’s Finance & Development magazine,
    Mian writes that our “dependence on credit to boost demand imperils the
    world economy.” As both consumers and governments around the world
    continue excessive borrowing, income inequality widens. That leads to
    more borrowing, and the vicious cycle continues.

    “The way we are living is not normal,” Mian tells Analyst News in an extensive interview. “We have become so addicted to debt that we are borrowing more than two times as much as we used to, for the same dollar
    of income that the economy is generating.”

    Analyst News spoke to Mian about his recent work and how it builds upon
    the research in House of Debt, the importance of balance in an economic
    system, and potential policy measures to reverse the “debt supercycle”
    that has become our new norm.

    This conversation has been edited for length and clarity.

    It’s been 10 years since your landmark book, House of Debt, came out. In
    it, you argued that severe recessions are caused by a huge buildup of
    consumer debt, which leads to a drop in household spending. Can you
    break down why consumer debt is so dangerous?

    What happens before a recession, the rise of debt, is as important to understand what happens after a recession. This is the economy’s way of generating demand. Some people are borrowing from others, who are
    lending because they don’t want to spend that money themselves. They
    want to hold on to that money in the form of wealth, so they put that
    money in the banks and the banks are essentially lending on their behalf.

    That money is going from lenders to borrowers, and then borrowers are
    the ones who are spending it by buying stuff — which is what actually
    moves the economy. The problem occurs if this process is too fast, if
    the volume of lending is too high. You can’t sustain a very high level
    of debt growth, because ultimately whoever is borrowing has to pay it
    back. You may come to a point where the lenders start demanding the
    money back.

    “The way we are living is not normal. We have become so addicted to debt
    that we are borrowing more than two times as much as we used to, for the
    same dollar of income that the economy is generating.”

    That’s the starting point of recessions. Spending that was happening
    because of this credit creation is no longer going into the economy. The
    money those individuals would have spent, they are now being forced to
    pay back to the lenders. When you demand your interest and principal
    back from them, they can only do that by cutting back further on their spending.

    None of that would be a problem if the lenders were going to spend that
    money back into the economy. Say I borrow from Bill Gates to buy a car.
    When I give that money back to Bill Gates, he already has enough cars in
    the world. He’s not going to buy an extra car. That’s not going to stimulate the economy at all.

    We argued strongly that in these kinds of downturns, you really want to
    share the risk by being lenient toward the borrowers, because that helps
    them to spend more into the economy.

    What would economic policies that promote risk sharing and leniency look
    like?

    The obvious one would be some notion of debt forgiveness, but you don’t
    have to go that far.

    Think of the moratorium on foreclosures that happened during the
    pandemic — that was a great thing. During the 2008 recession, one of our biggest criticisms of the Obama administration was that they did not put
    a moratorium on foreclosures. People’s house values were going down,
    they did not have money, they were getting laid off, they could not pay
    back their mortgages. Close to 4 million homeowners were forced into
    bankruptcy and their houses were foreclosed upon. There is no way an
    economy can instantaneously absorb 4 million new homes coming on the
    market. Who’s going to buy those homes? Nobody. That will only add to
    the glut of housing in the short term, which will reduce prices even
    more and make a bad situation even worse.

    Then there’s a bankruptcy arrangement: You can take up to a certain
    value of my wages, but you can’t garnish my wages forever. Europe has draconian debt prison laws where if I borrow a lot then you will garnish
    my wages as long as I’m unable to pay my debt with interest; those are
    very destructive and created a lot of trouble for countries like Greece,
    which literally went into a great depression because of the Europeans extracting too much from them. What happened to Greece post-2008 is the
    classic example of a country that suffered because of a lack of risk
    sharing.

    Another way is by reducing the implicit burden of debt by reducing
    interest payments — for example, by lowering interest rates. You can
    write financial contracts such that the interest rate automatically goes
    down, or such that principal plus interest payments are automatically diminished by, say, 10% and 20% based on how weak the economy is. The
    technical term for this would be state-contingent contracts, and we can
    add more risk sharing features that create flexibility.

    And this leniency is in the best interest of all parties, not just those
    in debt.

    Exactly. When I talk about risk sharing, it’s not this idea that I as an individual make a mistake and people should bail me out. When we are in collective trouble as a nation, we should collectively think of ways
    that we can help the indebted, the borrowers, the weaker sections of the economy.

    It’s not a moral argument. Even if you don’t care about philanthropy,
    I’m making a macroeconomic argument. I’m not saying to help the poor because it’s good to help the poor. Like that cliche that a rising tide
    lifts all boats — it’s literally true in these circumstances. It’s insights like that that make me passionate about the field of economics.
    It makes us understand those insights, that our collective good can be
    in helping those in need in those times of distress.

    You argued that debt forgiveness, rather than bank bailouts, is what
    would boost the economy. Where do bank bailouts fit into the equation?

    The full argument is not as much “don’t do bank bailouts in those circumstances,” it’s that just bailing out the bank is not adding sufficient demand into the economy. What you need to work on is the
    ultimate borrower. It’s not enough that if I’m not able to pay back a
    loan, that you just help the bank in the middle. To solve the problem
    fully, you have to actually help me, the ultimate borrower, as well.
    That was the missing piece in the 2008 recession.

    There is obviously the Wall Street-versus-Main Street view of the world,
    where Bernie Sanders says the government is just bailing out the rich
    people. That’s true. But we’re saying that even if you want to bail out
    the banks for whatever reason, you must not forget the indebted class
    that is really drowning in debt — and hurting the entire economy.

    The way the financial markets and banking industry are structured is
    very fragile by design. A bank has a very thin layer of equity, which is
    the piece that can absorb any potential losses on loans they make. For
    every dollar of equity, they typically borrow like $20 on top of that.

    Think of yourself as a bank. What you have is $5 of your own money, what
    I’m calling equity here, and $95 that you’ve borrowed. That $95 plus $5
    — those are the $100 you’ve lent to people like myself. Even if I
    default on only five cents out of the dollar that I’ve borrowed – just a
    5% loss — that actually is enough to completely wipe you out, because
    you only have $5 of your own equity in it.

    That’s what I mean by fragility. The financial sector is designed in a
    way that it cannot even withstand a 5% loss on its overall books. What
    ends up happening is that even if an economy has a little bit of trouble
    — literally 3% or 4% of the loans are in trouble — that puts incredible pressure on banks. They are so fragile that they can take the entire
    economy down with them once they get into trouble.

    At that point, it’s like the banks are holding a gun to our heads: Save
    us or we all go down. But there is a deeper question: Why did you allow
    the banks to be built as fragile as they are?

    In the intervening 10 years, how have you been able to expound on your
    initial argument? What is your prognosis?

    When the next big crisis came, the COVID crisis, it was to the credit of
    the Trump administration that they did respond much better. There was flexibility shown in terms of assistance provided to the people. The
    government stepped in and provided relief to the people. Banks were not
    allowed to foreclose on homes because everyone understood there’s a
    pandemic, so many people will not be able to pay anything because they
    don’t have a job. This time, the government really stepped in and
    protected people who suffered the most — the ones with weak balance
    sheets, less savings — and it really helped the economy in the long run.
    The recovery post-COVID recession was way faster and much stronger
    compared to the sluggish recovery after the 2008 recession. The economy actually never went back to the old trend then; this time, the U.S.
    economy did go back.

    “If your economy is going into these crises repeatedly and seems to be addicted to debt, we have to ask what’s going on.”

    But everything we’ve spoken about has focused on this kind of boom-bust cycle; what I’ve been doing over the last few years is asking a deeper question, which is why are we in this situation in the first place?
    Think of the good times before a recession. Why did we have to rely on
    debt to generate demand? Why do we need to borrow in the first place?
    You can talk about being lenient on consumers in times of collective
    trouble. But why do we get ourselves into that situation in the first
    place? If your economy is going into these crises repeatedly and seems
    to be addicted to debt, we have to ask what’s going on.

    Let’s dig into this question. Tell us about what you call the “debt supercycle” and what you’ve learned about this entrenched system of debt.

    We’ve been having these crises like the 2008 global crisis, but at the 10,000-foot level, let’s ignore all of that. There is a bigger cycle in
    the background. We don’t come out of these crises by relying less on
    debt; we seem to be coming out of each crisis by relying even more on
    debt than before. It’s like if I’m [unwell] and decide to take more of
    the drug that got me in trouble in the first place.

    Let’s say I borrow $100,000 from you, build a business, generate
    $200,000. I give you back your $100,000 and now I have $100,000 of
    profit. This is what we want. This is not bad debt. This is productive
    debt. When entrepreneurial people borrow to invest in good ideas, to
    create dry cleaning services and manufacturing plants, they can make
    even more money. We should be facilitating lending and borrowing, if
    debt is being used to generate new businesses.

    That’s the Econ 101 description of when debt is productive and when it’s useful for the economy. But something seems to be very off. If you were
    using $1 of debt to generate $1 of income in the year 1980, today,
    you’re borrowing twice as much — and even more, collectively — to generate the same dollar of debt.

    I’m talking about tens of trillions of dollars of additional debt. What
    is happening? What is this additional debt doing? The answer, if you
    look at the data, is that none of that additional debt is being used to
    start new businesses. We are still investing as much as we were in 1980.
    But all of this additional debt is being borrowed for consumption
    purposes — not for investment, but for consumption.

    Why is this a problem? Let’s go back to Econ 101. Instead of me
    borrowing $100,000 from you and generating $100,000 in profit, I’ve been borrowing from you and just eating it up. We have nothing to show for
    it. And you don’t give me that money for free; you demand an interest
    from me. Ask yourself the following question: If you are lending
    $100,000 to me, and you’re demanding some return on that, and I’m not
    doing anything with that money, how is that sustainable? The only way I
    can pay you back that money tomorrow is if I take my existing salary and
    I cut down my consumption, my expenditure.

    This is the ultimate truth of debt. It’s basic common sense; I’m not
    making any subtle arguments here. If people borrow for pure consumption purposes, it only makes them poorer in the long run. Because the only
    way you can pay back the initial debt with interest is by becoming
    poorer — that is, by reducing my consumption from what it would have
    been if I had not borrowed.

    It seems like an unwinnable battle.

    It is. Now, given that all of the debt essentially from 1980 onwards has
    been borrowed for pure consumption purposes, it has to be the case that
    the borrowing class is becoming poorer in that sense that they have to
    cut back on their spending. That’s the only way they can pay back the
    lending class, which is of course the richer class.

    Given the scale of this borrowing, it’s not possible to do that. They
    cannot cut back their spending so much that they can all pay back the
    returns that the rich would have been expecting in 1980, 1990s. So
    something else has been happening as a result of that. Which is that
    interest rates have been falling from the 1980s onwards to a point when
    2008 hit, and all of us remember that time. Interest rates went all the
    way down to zero and stayed there, until very recently.

    This is the more subtle, technical argument. People were borrowing these incredible amounts of dollars; they cannot afford to pay that money
    back. And so the system adjusts for that inability to pay back the debt,
    by reducing the interest rate on debt. This is what I refer to as the
    indebted demand force. We were the first to highlight this very
    important force that’s been operating in the global economy, that has
    been pushing interest rates down.

    Once the economy becomes addicted to debt, to generate demand and
    spending from the borrowing class, it keeps pushing the world to an
    environment of lower and lower interest rates — up to a point where it
    cannot do that anymore because interest rates are stuck at zero. They
    cannot go below zero, and when you reach that environment, the only
    place left for this economy to go is for the government to step in and
    start borrowing and spending. That’s what we’ve seen in the world at large.

    At some point, the consumer borrows so much they cannot borrow anymore.
    We kind of reached that place in like 2008, 2009. If you look at the
    economy after that, it is the government that has been borrowing and
    spending. People talk about the U.S. government debt that’s been rising
    many trillions of dollars higher. And it has to, because the economy is
    relying on debt to boost spending.

    But why do we need all this debt?

    We argue that the deeper problem is extreme and rising inequality. The
    reason individuals, and now governments, have to borrow these incredible
    sums of money is because there is no such thing as net debt. It’s always zero. Who is on the other side? For the world to be borrowing these
    trillions of dollars of debt, there has to be someone who’s lending
    these trillions of dollars of debt. It’s the super rich, who are the
    ones lending more and more. That’s why debt is rising. Why are they
    lending more and more and again? Because they’re making more and more
    money, but they cannot consume more.

    If you were earning $10 million in 1980, today you are earning close to
    double that amount at a time when the rest of the people are still on
    average earning the same in today’s dollars. That’s the scale of rising inequality.

    Let’s say you’re earning $10 million a year — you can buy the best
    house, car, vacations, all of that. Now imagine I make you richer. You
    will not know what to do with that money because you already have
    everything. So what you’ll try to do is generate more wealth: put that
    money in some bank or hedge fund, and search for demand. That is what
    the financial sector does. It tries to lend that money back to someone
    who will be willing to spend that.

    The only way this economy can try to survive is if it finds someone to
    take that money and spend it, and the only way you can do that in the
    modern economy is through debt.

    And that borrowing is going to be unproductive, as you said. But why
    can’t it go toward generating business rather than consumption?

    The reason this has not added more to productive capacity is because if
    the ownership of productive assets is already very concentrated —
    because you own the productive sector, that’s why you’re rich — and if the economy is already finding it hard to generate new demand, you would
    not want to.

    You’re basically asking, why are you not using the $10 million to, say,
    start a new auto company or to expand your existing auto plants? Well,
    where are you going to find the customers? Because the returns to that
    new investment will also go to you, but you’re not going to buy an extra
    car because you already have all the cars you need. The concentration of productive assets in the hands of a few in the first place itself
    becomes a limitation to why you cannot use that debt for productive
    purposes.

    That can further exacerbate as the economy grows. So in some of the
    recent work, we have shown that this rising concentration can lead to
    very low interest rates and that lowering of interest rates actually
    makes the productive sector even more concentrated. You can borrow money
    so cheap, why are you not borrowing and investing? Well, because you
    have so much power now, so you focus on monopolizing the sectors rather
    than expanding them.

    When the initial problem is extreme inequality, the only way you can
    lend it out the new savings put back into the banking sector is for unproductive purposes. That’s exactly what has happened over the last
    30, 40 years. It would have been better if this money could have been
    used for productive purposes. But that has not happened. And everything
    I’ve just described is a global phenomenon.

    What scares you about it? If we continue as we are globally, what’s the ultimate consequence?

    I think we’re already living in the times of the ultimate consequence.
    If you conceptually walked through the full set of arguments, I’m saying
    [you accumulate] very high levels of debt and you reach this world of
    zero interest rates and so on. We are already there — we’re 10 years
    into it. We had the COVID shock, there was some inflation, governments borrowing [more and more]. The other major thing that’s starting to
    happen is all of these military conflicts, which only makes governments
    borrow even more. This can potentially raise interest rates.

    The ultimate problem here is really one of this imbalance and
    inequality. Technically, you can continue to run the world like this.
    We’re talking about an ecosystem, and in ecosystems, it would be a very extreme event to say, everyone dies and the world [ends]. We are already
    living in the consequences of this extreme, imbalanced world that can
    only kind of move forward by binging on debt. But that’s no way to live.

    People think there is a crisis in the future. What they are not
    realizing is that they are living in a crisis. You’re expecting
    something worse to happen. You need a little bit more self-realization
    to say this is not normal.

    “We are already living in the consequences of this extreme, imbalanced
    world that can only kind of move forward by binging on debt. But that’s
    no way to live.”

    Remember, when people are relying on debt for consumption, they are
    becoming poorer in the long run. And if the reason for all this debt is
    this extreme inequality, what else is going to happen? Well, this small minority is going to become more and more powerful. And they start using
    that influence politically, of course, and the politics start to become
    more and more dysfunctional. It becomes more polarized; you start to see
    more and more that this notion of a common good is not being represented
    in the political system.

    About 10 years ago, someone who has been to the highest avenues of power
    told me our democracy has been hacked. Now it’s very obvious. This is
    one of the consequences of a system being highly imbalanced, where
    economic power has just gotten concentrated in the very few hands. If
    you need to use debt to push the system forward, you can always do that.
    But it starts to have these political implications.

    There is a sense of hopelessness among young people that wasn’t there in
    the ’60s, ’70s, ’80s. The younger generations born after World War II were very optimistic about the future. Take the U.S. median wage and ask yourself: How many years of savings would it take to buy your first
    home, assuming you’re not fortunate enough that your parents already
    have a home to give you, like half the population? It’s many times what
    it would have taken in the ’70s. The reason is this debt-based economy
    that we have addicted ourselves to: High levels of debt means your
    interest rates have to go down to zero, and one implication is that the
    value of assets like houses and land continues to rise.

    But look at the irony of this — it’s rising inequality that’s making interest rates fall by addicting the economy to debt. It’s making rich
    people who already have assets even richer because that’s how financial markets work. And there’s no way you can get out of that, without many different forms of tax policy and so on.

    It’s not like there is danger on the horizon. We’re already living in a world with this disease and it is afflicting the next generations. We
    need to solve it today.

    Rebalancing and reversing the debt supercycle calls for structural
    changes so that growth is more equitable. What would these structural
    changes look like?

    In the economy, we say there’s a supply side and the demand side. To rebalance the economy to get out of this addiction to debt, we need to
    think of changes both on the supply side and the demand side.

    The investment ideas need to be worked on on the supply side of the
    economy to make the growth process more equitable. One is we need a lot
    more investment and regulation that would make the returns to the
    economy more equitable.

    That requires a very different way of organizing ourselves and
    regulating ourselves. There are many challenges, like the rise of AI,
    robots, technology. There are very serious issues of how you cannot just completely run a free market world and just hope all of those issues
    will settle properly on their own. Economics is a serious science, and
    we know that cannot happen.

    One way of structural change that we need is investing more through the
    public sector, through public investments — something that the U.S. used
    to do in the ’60s and ’50s but doesn’t do much now.

    Reducing payroll taxes, aggressive forms of taxation, and making the
    taxation system more progressive are ideas that are working on the
    demand side of the economy. Whoever wins the lottery — on who gets new technology, monopoly power and so on — will become very rich. But you
    have to have a much more reasonable system of taxation. The taxation
    system needs to be more progressive, but on the right dimension. We
    actually need to reduce taxes for the middle and lower middle class —
    for example, payroll taxes — and we need to raise taxes at the very top
    end of the distribution. A wealth tax at the top end, the 1% or less of
    the population, would very much help.

    For a country like the U.S., the demand side structural changes are more important, relatively. But if you were to start talking about Africa or developing countries, the supply side issues are really first order there.

    As inequality is growing, what is the viability of potential structural
    changes given the power concentration?

    The reason good change does not happen is because the structure of the
    status quo is such that the incentives of people in power are all
    aligned to resist what the system and society actually need.

    This is nothing new. When societies are collectively stuck in a bad
    situation, it is often primarily because of this particular problem —
    what you might call the political economy problem. If you were to
    propose those solutions, you will face active resistance.

    The other reality is that all of us have agency in terms of
    communicating ideas, in terms of convincing people to change. That’s how
    we have voting and political parties. So I don’t want to be completely pessimistic. I think it’s good that we have some notion of democracy, as
    bad as it might be, and there is still the possibility that we can
    engage in a societal dialogue.

    While our selfish individual interests are for self-preservation and preservation of the status quo, there is a bigger force always in play
    as well: Nature also has a corrective mechanism. I’m reverting to
    philosophy here, as we don’t fully understand all of this. But there is
    a greater sense of depression, a sense of anger. There is something
    behind that.

    Think of political shifts in the U.S. — I could not have imagined
    someone like Trump coming up to power on the right, or on the left
    someone like Bernie Sanders gaining traction. But you can see people are
    more willing to take extremes. When the system itself is not working for
    people at large, there is a sense of frustration that becomes
    heightened, and people start to listen more to what were earlier,
    unthinkable ideas.

    Those ideas can be crazy and make it even worse. But sometimes those unthinkable ideas may be the right places to go. I’m not holding my
    breath, but nature may force our hand.

    Ismat Mangla is a former business journalist and the managing editor of
    Analyst News.

    DEBTECONOMICSECONOMYQ&A

    SHARE

    --- SoupGate-Win32 v1.05
    * Origin: fsxNet Usenet Gateway (21:1/5)